12/ This is because a robot subsidy can alleviate markup distortions and, by lowering the user cost of robots, a subsidy reallocates production toward large, automating firms that have high productivity, bringing aggregate output closer to the efficient level.
04.06.2025 03:32 β π 1 π 0 π¬ 0 π 0
11/ Under our calibration, a modest robot subsidy (about 1.41% of the value of robots) maximizes the steady-state welfare, yielding a welfare gain equivalent to about 4.23% of steady-state consumption compared to the laissez-faire benchmark.
04.06.2025 03:32 β π 0 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
10/ Under our calibration, the model predicts that a 40% fall in the relative price of robotsβobserved during the past two decadesβcan explain ~50% of the rise in sales concentration in the U.S. manufacturing and ~25% of the divergence between sales and employment concentration.
04.06.2025 03:32 β π 0 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
9/ the Annual Business Survey: The adoption rate of robots in 2016-2018 by firms in the top percentile of the employment distribution within 6-digit industries was about 3 times of the adoption rate among firms in the 50th to 75th percentile (5.1% vs. 1.7%).
04.06.2025 03:32 β π 0 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
8/ We calibrate the model to match several moments observed in the U.S. manufacturing sector. Our calibrated model predicts that the usage of automation technology is highly skewed toward a small fraction of large firms, in line with the cross-sectional evidence from ...
04.06.2025 03:32 β π 1 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
7/ Since robots substitute for workers, the expansion of those large firms relies more on robots than on workers. Thus, a rise in automation raises sales concentration more than employment concentration, as we observe in the data.
04.06.2025 03:32 β π 0 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
6/ Automation improves a firmβs labor productivity, allowing large, robot-using firms to expand their sales share further. This economy-of-scale effect leads to a positive connection between automation and sales concentration.
04.06.2025 03:32 β π 0 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
5/ Operating the automation technology incurs a fixed cost, but it reduces the marginal cost of production. Larger firms are more likely to automate because they have higher productivity, higher market power, and thus higher profits.
04.06.2025 03:32 β π 2 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
4/ To understand the empirical link between automation and industry concentration, we construct a dynamic general equilibrium model featuring heterogeneous firms, endogenous automation decisions, and variable markups.
04.06.2025 03:32 β π 1 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
3/ employment concentration. These empirical relations are robust when we estimate the correlations using an instrumental variable (IV) approach.
04.06.2025 03:32 β π 0 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
2/ manufacturing and ~25% of the divergence between sales and employment concentration.
We first document that, at the industry level, robot density has a significantly positive correlation with sales concentration but a small and insignificant correlation with ...
04.06.2025 03:32 β π 0 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
1/ A thread on βAutomation and the Rise of Superstar Firmsβ recently published @ Journal of Monetary Economics. Link to the paper:
drive.google.com/file/d/1KvVA...
Summary: The rise in automation in the past two decades explains ~50% of the rise in sales concentration in the US ...
04.06.2025 03:32 β π 4 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
New at JIE: "Reshoring, automation, and labor markets under trade uncertainty", by Hamid Firooz (@hamid-firooz.bsky.social), Sylvain Leduc and Zheng Liu
doi.org/10.1016/j.ji...
12.05.2025 16:13 β π 5 π 2 π¬ 1 π 0
11/11 Instead, it raises unemployment, thereby turning the pro-competitive gains from trade negative. In the language of Arkolakis et al. (2019), I show that the pro-competitive gains from trade liberalization can be even more βelusiveβ in the presence of labor market frictions.
25.04.2025 03:37 β π 0 π 0 π¬ 0 π 0
10/ resulting in a more efficient allocation of resources and therefore leading to positive pro-competitive gains from trade. In frictional labor markets, however, the increase in firmsβ responsiveness does not costlessly shift employment toward more efficient firms.
25.04.2025 03:37 β π 0 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
9/ taking labor market frictions into account makes the pro-competitive gains from trade liberalization negative. In the absence of search frictions, trade liberalization makes firms more responsive to their idiosyncratic shocks via variable markups, ...
25.04.2025 03:37 β π 0 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
8/ The surge in unemployment caused by variable markups tends to reduce the pro-competitive gains from trade in the steady state. Interestingly, I show that while abstracting from labor market frictions in my framework implies positive pro-competitive gains from trade, ...
25.04.2025 03:37 β π 0 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
7/ This in turn increases the labor elasticities of revenue, which makes firmsβ employment decisions more responsive to their idiosyncratic shocks. More responsiveness to shocks increases unemployment and residual wage inequality in a frictional labor market.
25.04.2025 03:37 β π 0 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
6/ The counterfactual outcomes under variable markups are more consistent with Colombia's trade liberalization.
The link between trade, markups, and labor market outcomes is due to trade liberalization increasing product market competition, thereby raising demand elasticities.
25.04.2025 03:37 β π 0 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
5/ In particular, I show that once markups are allowed to respond to trade liberalization, unemployment and residual wage inequality rise almost three times more than in a model with constant markups (in the steady state).
25.04.2025 03:37 β π 0 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
4/ I develop and estimate a dynamic general equilibrium model of international trade featuring
endogenously variable markups to show that trade-induced changes in markups have important
impacts on labor market outcomes in a frictional labor market.
25.04.2025 03:37 β π 0 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
3/ while Colombiaβs trade liberalization in the 1990s raises its real income by 1.7% (in the steady state) under constant markups, accounting for variable markups reduces these gains to only 0.3%.
25.04.2025 03:37 β π 0 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
2/ Moreover, the pro-competitive βgainsβ from trade in a frictional labor market are quite negativeβthat is, the steady-state welfare gains are smaller under variable markups than those under constant markups:
25.04.2025 03:37 β π 0 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
1/ A thread on βThe Pro-Competitive Consequences of Trade in Frictional Labor Marketsβ published @jintlecon.bsky.social. Link to the paper:
drive.google.com/file/d/1gNpO...
Summary: Taking variable markups into account in frictional labor markets reduces the gains from trade liberalization by 80%.
25.04.2025 03:37 β π 7 π 2 π¬ 1 π 0
Economist at King's College London. Trade, development, migration, political madness, grand corruption. pierrelouisvezina@weebly.com
Assistant Professor of Economics at U of Delaware. Labor/Migration
https://www.parag-mahajan.com
Post-doc @UC Louvain
https://aurelien-goutsmedt.com
History macro, inflation, econ policy & energy since the 70s
#Political_Economy #Central_Banks
#Rstats #nlp #networks #bibliometrics
Managing editor journals.openedition.org/oeconomia
Economics at North Central College, PhD University of Connecticut, development and health, Peruvian π΅πͺ, dog lover πΎ, she/her
Senior Economist at the Census Bureau
Macro Labor, Market Power, and Firm Dynamics
Views are my own
Assistant Professor, Department of Economics @unibocconi, @IGIER, Research Fellow @cepr.org, Associated Researcher @ofceparis. #macroeconomics #IO #network
π³οΈβπ
πChicago
πFlorida State University
π Economics
π³οΈPolitics
PhD in economics and visiting lecturer at University of Tartu, Post-doc at Politecnico di Milano - Dastu. Unapologetically European and World federalist.
Macroeconomist | Assistant Professor @CEMFI
www.federicokochen.com
Economist working on topics in Macro-labor and behavioral macro, currently at the Federal Reserve Board. @utaustinecon.bsky.social, Delhi School of Economics alum.
Economist working in international macro. Interested in LATAM firms, banks and labor markets. UMich Econ alumni. Views are my own.
Economics and and data-driven insights for equitable development. https://egc.yale.edu
Field: Emerging markets economics: trade, stabilization, and growth.
Associate professor of economics, School of Economics and Business, Alberto Hurtado University, Santiago, Chile.
π #1 Amazon Best Seller β Business Mentoring
π₯ Bottom-Up Breakthrough is changing how orgs grow
π‘ Driving impact w/ Bottom-Up Communication
π Buy my book: a.co/d/fORQgrn
π bottom-up.ca | LinkedIn.com/in/rich-dunbar
The Institution for Social and Policy Studies at Yale advances interdisciplinary research to shape public policy and support democratic deliberation.
Economist. Opinions are my own. RT/likes - not endorsement | PhD @UofR | Research Advisor | Research Fellow @HooverInst @CEPR @iza
Associate Professor, Economics, YorkU | Inequality, Technological Change, Occupations, Skill Investments | π¨π· π¨π¦ π³οΈβπ
U Carlos III de Madrid prof, interested in life & work in frictional labor markets. http://ludovisschers.eu; team https://labourflows.co.uk/; Cesifo,IZA,EFI & Stone Centre; RT.ne.endorsed; Ordered my lattes in π³π± πͺπΊ πͺπΈ π΄σ §σ ’σ ³σ £σ ΄σ Ώ π¬π§ π¨π¦ πΊπΈ
Labor Economist, Deputy Head Inequality and public policy group @zew.de, affiliated with #UniMannheim, PhD @uc3meconomics.bsky.social, mother of 1 son, lives in Frankfurt, born in Greece
https://sites.google.com/site/efiadamopoulou/
Principal Economic Advisor at the Inter-American Development Bank | Affiliate @cesifo.org | All views here are mine. RTs do not imply endorsement.