Theoretical Economics Volume 20, Issue 3 (July 2025) is now online econtheory.org
23.07.2025 16:18 β π 0 π 1 π¬ 0 π 0@davidragrawal.bsky.social
Professor UC Irvine Economics; Editor-in-Chief ITAX; Research on tax, fiscal competition, local policy, RST/VAT, inequality & mobility https://sites.socsci.uci.edu/~dagrawa4/
Theoretical Economics Volume 20, Issue 3 (July 2025) is now online econtheory.org
23.07.2025 16:18 β π 0 π 1 π¬ 0 π 0Last day to submit! Looking forward to seeing you in Berlin!
15.04.2025 17:34 β π 2 π 1 π¬ 0 π 0π¨ 1 week left! π¨
Working on local public finance or fiscal federalism?
Present your research in Berlin π©πͺ
π
July 7β8, 2025
π Harnack-Haus
ποΈ Keynote: @davidragrawal.bsky.social (UC Irvine)
βοΈ Travel & stay covered
π© Apply by April 15 β events.tax.mpg.de/event/10/
Please share this! β»οΈ
Local public economics and federalism are important!
I'm excited to return to Berlin to give the keynote at this conference on local public finance issues around the world.
Travel funding available!
Submit your local PF papers here:
events.tax.mpg.de/event/10/
Excited to serve another term as Editor-in-chief of @itaxjournal.bsky.social with this new fantastic team!
20.02.2025 22:34 β π 7 π 2 π¬ 0 π 0Thanks to both Ron and Nadine for their service to the public finance community, especially during the crazy pandemic years. I learned a lot & enjoyed working with them over the last four years where submissions to the journal almost doubled!
And follow @itaxjournal.bsky.social which is new here!
Elasticities are endogenous and government choices. Eg they can be influenced by sale or things like zoning. We wanted to add this to the model but will save for future work
31.01.2025 06:59 β π 1 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0An interesting question is where the optimal borders are in light of this heterogeneity
31.01.2025 06:58 β π 1 π 0 π¬ 0 π 0Thanks! Can you say more about the model application with SALT?
30.01.2025 07:10 β π 0 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0This is really cool! Have always thought this was a missing extension, particularly in the SALT context
29.01.2025 12:25 β π 0 π 1 π¬ 1 π 0Check out the paper here:
econtheory.org/ojs/index.ph...
We are grateful to @florianscheuer.bsky.social for his extensive comments as editor and for the three excellent referees he selected, especially Referee B whose reports were some of the most insightful I have ever seen.
Highly recommend the process at
@econtheory.bsky.social
In ongoing work, we verify our theoretical commodity tax result empirically. That paper is coming soon!
Finally, we discussion how our results might be applicable to spatial price competition with multiple firms, to spatial voting models, or to border effects in trade.
Capital competition models with two jurisdictions place assumptions on moving costs.
With three jurisdictions, the distribution of moving costs for firms plays the same role as population density.
Again bigger jurisdiction can set lower rates!
Profit shifting models often have 2 jurisdictions and quadratic costs.
We generalize to three jurisdictions with a more general convex cost function for profit shifting.
The higher derivatives of the cost function play the same role as population density.
Finally, we show the result generalizes beyond spatial commodity tax competition to models of profit taxation (Keen and Konrad ) or capital taxation (Mongrain and
Wilson).
And we go even further to show there exist a distribution function and jurisdiction boundaries such that the complete ordering of tax rates reverses from the rankings of populations.
28.01.2025 23:30 β π 0 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0In other words, the denominators of the optimal tax rates are now different!
28.01.2025 23:30 β π 0 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0Classic result can be overturned b/c with 3 jurisdictions, a jurisdiction can attract cross-border shoppers from 2βinstead of 1 jurisdiction
Thus, tax base sensitivities are no longer equal
Elasticities in Ramsey rule depend on size and on the average base change at 2 borders!
We conclude that we can find a population jurisdiction with three jurisdictions such that P1 > P2 and T1 < T2.
That is, a smaller jurisdiction can set a higher
tax rate than the next largest jurisdiction.
Then show if the border between 1/2 makes 1 smaller, T1 - T2 is decreasing.
Thus, reduce this border a small amount such that
T1 < T2 > T3
But under the perturbed population distribution we have P1 > P2 > P3.
QED (many complex details in paper)
Small perturbation results in P1 > P2 > P3
Although the initial equilibrium satisfied the assumptions for existence, the perturbed density may not.
But we prove the equilibrium of the original unperturbed game is also an equilibrium to a perturbed game! T1 = T2 > T3
Finally, we generalize this result for an arbitrary f(x) and asymmetric jurisdictions.
Proof strategy:
Start from a Nash eq where population P1 = P2 > P3 and taxes are T1 = T2 > T3
Make a specific population perturbation that changes populations but leaves tax bases unchanged
We first prove smaller places set higher rates using a simple example:
Population distribution is triangular.
2 jurisdictions are symmetric and have a common border at the lowest density point.
Then for a certain range of their lengths, we get
little t > big T despite p < P
First we need to show an equilibrium exists and is unique.
If f(x) is log-concave and satisfies one other mild condition, then the game is supermodular and existence follows.
To do this, simply add a third jurisdiction with a general f(x).
28.01.2025 23:30 β π 0 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0However, relaxing both the assumption of 2 jurisdictions and a uniform population distribution allows for a much richer pattern of equilibrium tax rates
A smaller jurisdiction will set a higher rate than a bigger if there are multiple competitors and if population is not uniform
In other words, Nash taxes depend on
-tax bases: numerators in these equations that differ
-tax base sensitivities: denominators in these equations, which are the same for both jurisdictions.
On the margin, they compete for the same people!
Intuition:
in the case of two jurisdictions, the marginal tax base of lowering taxes is the same for both the large and small jurisdiction (eg dBase/dT = dBase/dt)
Elasticities only depend on size, not on sensitivity of the base.
Marginal consumer same for both jurisdictions!
We keep everything the same
except population is not uniform, but distributed according to f(x) that is continuous and differentiable
Then, we can show the big jurisdiction's tax rate is always greater than the little's regardless of f(x).