anyway if Britain indirectly benefited from fighting all those wars (financial development, boost to arms industry, etc.) these benefits accrued because very few wars were actually fought on British soil !
23.09.2025 14:59 β π 5 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
The vast majority of wars that Britain participated in (mostly through subsidies to other states) were a big waste of time & treasure because their aims went well beyond those narrow interests. And European wars were not good for British trade with Europe, period.
23.09.2025 14:58 β π 1 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
the trade that mattered for Britain before the Industrial Revolution was the trade with America and with Western Europe. Protecting the trade with America required defending the American colonies prior to independence plus Jamaica/Barbados.
23.09.2025 14:57 β π 1 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
precisely! though check out my clarification (a separate thread)
23.09.2025 14:26 β π 2 π 0 π¬ 0 π 0
IMO an important, but near totally neglected, reason that England was 'first' to undergo an industrial revolution, but continental industrialisation was delayed -- was precisely that so many wars were fought in 1500-1800 by European states on European soil.
23.09.2025 14:24 β π 10 π 1 π¬ 1 π 0
Did warfare drive the evolution of complex societies over thousands of years Γ la Morris or Turchin? -- YES
BUT did European wars in 1500-1800 advance or retard a countryβs economic development relative to England?
My answer: RETARD
23.09.2025 14:22 β π 11 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
Does historical warfare (e.g., 1400-1900) predict high-capacity states in 2025? -- YES
Did warfare make the average European state more capable of extracting resources from its population than the Chinese state, ca 1800? -- YES
23.09.2025 14:21 β π 6 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
Many misunderstood my meaning so here is a clarification.
I was NOT saying the social science lit arguing that war => state formation/capacity is wrong.
There is a subtle distinction between that question and the narrower historical question of the little divergence within western Europe.
23.09.2025 14:20 β π 14 π 1 π¬ 1 π 0
Preexisting characteristics include, did they have a lot of merchants, did they have a lot of peasants, were they very urbanised, etc. Whereas the state capacity literature which invokes Tilly is driven by testing the simple causal hypothesis that βwars => state capacityβ.
23.09.2025 14:11 β π 2 π 0 π¬ 0 π 0
I do think Tillly's meaning is pretty clear in conjunction with the text. For Tilly, states *selected* into the types of fiscal capacity (coercive or consensual or some intermediate path) based on preexisting characteristics of those states, as much as wars caused centralisation and state capacity.
23.09.2025 14:11 β π 2 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
I always thought coercive versus consensual was the better dichotomy than coercion- versus capital-intensive...
23.09.2025 14:11 β π 2 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
( assuming theyβve even read the book )
22.09.2025 21:03 β π 3 π 0 π¬ 0 π 0
Tilly: βstates having access to a combination of large rural populations, capitalists, and relatively commercialized economy won outβ
the element of selection in Tilly is stronger than the simple βwar => state formationβ formula that most EH take away from Coercion, Capital, and European States
22.09.2025 21:03 β π 5 π 0 π¬ 2 π 0
technical innovations are the best way to rescue the positive role of war in European development; and although some people have made that argument, itβs much less popular than the state capacity & Malthusian arguments; which just goes to show you the decadence of economic historians :-) ;-)
22.09.2025 20:33 β π 3 π 0 π¬ 0 π 0
but Iβm not saying being spared from war is sufficient for anything
22.09.2025 20:29 β π 1 π 0 π¬ 0 π 0
The best case for the state capacity argument is that if you fight a lot of wars but NOT on your own territory & often by using proxies, like England who esp in the 18th century provided subsidies to states fighting wars far more than supplying troops & saw almost no fighting on its own soil
22.09.2025 19:16 β π 2 π 0 π¬ 2 π 0
IMO these arguments may or may not be valid compared with Asia but within the European, the state capacity thing is overrated because actually looking at European states, you can see that the urgency of war reinforced some very unmodern & frankly stupid methods of taxation.
22.09.2025 19:14 β π 6 π 1 π¬ 1 π 0
(i.e., mortality from direct & indirect causes through constant wars relieved population pressure low & ergo kept per capita incomes higher )
22.09.2025 19:12 β π 2 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
Generally, many? most? EH think that wars were good for European economic development, especially in the very long run; and there are two proposed mechanisms. Wars promote state centralisation & built state capacity, esp. fiscal & bureaucratic capacity. And/or wars were good for Malthusian reasonsβ¦
22.09.2025 19:10 β π 2 π 1 π¬ 2 π 0
very long-term, like on a multi-thousand year scale, different story. I'm a fan of this book
22.09.2025 14:28 β π 2 π 1 π¬ 0 π 0
( My default is that Ogilvie is always correct, unless proven otherwise. That is the opposite of my default on AJR :-)
22.09.2025 13:36 β π 12 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
Wars were mostly bad for European economic development. Might be obvious to ordinary people, but it's not considered obvious in economic history. But I think it's obvious ;-)
Below from @sheilaghogilvie.bsky.social
22.09.2025 13:36 β π 117 π 20 π¬ 4 π 3
( Similar in France: military competition made prerevoutionary French finances stupider, not cleverer! )
22.09.2025 13:20 β π 5 π 0 π¬ 0 π 0
I side with Ogilvie: German states used βarchaicβ means of financing wars & made all kinds of side deals which strengthened guilds, manorial rights, mercantile privileges, making Germany look 'feudal' & 'backward' circa 1800.
22.09.2025 13:20 β π 8 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
(2) War retarded German economic development & by implication delayed German industrialisation. 'Germany' in the 16th c had been dynamic & innovative. War not only destroyed physically but inter-state competition actually worsened institutions. This view is associated (most recently) with Ogilvie.
22.09.2025 13:18 β π 4 π 1 π¬ 1 π 0
(1) βModern economic growthβ in the German-speaking lands emerged after the war, gradually, as Smithian growth took hold via territorial consolidation & market integration, plus improved institutions via the usual βwar made the stateβ mechanism. This view is associated (most recently) with Pfister.
22.09.2025 13:16 β π 5 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
There are two conflicting views on The Thirty Yearsβ War and the onset of the German Industrial Revolution:
22.09.2025 13:16 β π 4 π 0 π¬ 1 π 0
( The German empireβs free cities shouldered the financial burden of the war by taxation & debt. Some of that taxation was basically protection money paid to armies to avoid being ransacked by them. War-time destruction of urban wealth argues had long-term negative consequences. )
22.09.2025 13:15 β π 6 π 1 π¬ 1 π 0
Happy to see @victoriagierok.bsky.social argue β βThe state made war and war made the stateβ does not describe very aptly what happened during pre-industrial Europeβs largest warsβ in a recent paper on wealth destruction in urban Germany during the Thirty Years' War.
ora.ox.ac.uk/objects/uuid...
22.09.2025 13:14 β π 20 π 5 π¬ 1 π 1
the Arab-Israeli conflict is severely underrated as a cause of it IMO
21.09.2025 15:52 β π 1 π 0 π¬ 0 π 0
Historian, currently at the Wissenschaftskolleg zu Berlin. https://www.davidedgerton.org/
Incoming Humboldt fellow at Bamberg | Historian of early modern French global commerce - political/economic/social/maritime history π«π·ππ³οΈβπ | Privilege, Economy and State in Old Regime France out now - download for free http://t.ly/NMc17
Economic and social historian of the early modern world, innovation, industrialisation and all things cotton. Assistant Prof at UCL History. Chair of the Womenβs Committee of the Economic History Society.
Professor of Development Studies, LSE | Research: Ethnicity, Nationalism, African Politics, Political Economy of Development | Ealing, UK resident but Evanston, IL native | website: https://personal.lse.ac.uk/greened/
Thirty Years War. Digital Humanities. Other Stuff.
Professor of Economic History at London School of Economics. Works on Economic History of Identity and Historical Political Economy. Website: https://www.lse.ac.uk/Economic-History/People/Faculty-and-teachers/Dr-Mohamed-Saleh
Development / Urban / Macro economist at BU. On the 24-25 Job Market
https://pdeffebach.github.io/
Exploring the past to shape the future πππ
Follow for research & talks by world-class scholars.
Blog: https://blogs.lse.ac.uk/economichistory/
Assistant Professor at Toulouse School of Economics (TSE)
https://victorgay.netlify.app/
Assistant Prof WUR. (African) economic history: migration, inequality, agricultural development. NWO Veni project: East Africa & the Great Depression
Author of #Economica: A Global History of Women, Wealth & Power. Resident economic historian on BBC Radio 4 #UnderstandTheEconomy. Fellow of the Royal Historical Society & RSA.
Historian of globalisation, capitalism and economic cultures | Professor at The University of Manchester | Director of the Centre for Economic Cultures
Robert Garrett Professor of Politics and Public Affairs, Princeton University
RT β Endorsement
Historical Economics, Economic History and everything in between. European Review of Economic History. Repost does not imply publication offer. Posts by Benjamin Chatterton.
The Past and Present Society: making cutting edge social history accessible since 1952. Our journal Past & Present is published by Oxford University Press.
https://academic.oup.com/past
Official account of the Social Science History Association. Supporting social science history since 1974, we host an annual meeting and publish a journal. More about us can be found at www.ssha.org
Assistant Professor at LSE, Visiting Yale. Political Economy, Gender, Culture and Narrative, and Early Modern and Modern China.